OF PEOPLE, CURVES, AND AUTISM
We begin, as we often do, by passing along some tidbits from our
mailbag.
Our editorial segment "Sketch of a Vibrant Life" (Fall 2000),
written by Mary Boger to commemorate Annette Rubinstein's 90th
birthday, prompted a kind letter to Annette from Justine Roberts of
Mill Valley, California. After noting Dr. Rubinstein's work at the
Robert Louis Stevenson School and wishing there had been more
details, Roberts writes: "It was interesting to find that current-year issues of S&S are located on the "High-Use" shelves of UC-Berkeley's main Periodicals Room, along with Time and a relatively
small number of other titles. On the other hand, all of this
year's issues were in place, i.e., none stolen or hidden, which
suggests that S&S is probably not quite at the top of the
popularity list." We love to learn that SCIENCE & SOCIETY is
widely available, even to non-subscribers. This may be wishful
thinking, but I would like to suggest an alternative interpretation
of the fact that none of our issues were stolen or hidden. Perhaps
we have a more principled readership than Time! Our issues are
widely read, but by students who understand that whatever use they
can make of S&S' contents depends on others also having access to
these ideas. (I know, I know, keep dreaming.)
Another West Coast reader, Doris Brin Walker (hailing from San
Francisco), notes the reference, in "Editorial Perspectives,"
Summer 2000, to Marx's "proposition that humankind only sets itself
problems when the conditions for their solution have come into
existence." She then comments:
Marx wrote long before the atom was split. Humankind
has now set itself a problem for which, nuclear
physicists have concluded, there is no solution: the
disposition of nuclear wastes, particularly those
resulting from the production of nuclear bombs and other
nuclear weapons.
This is followed by an expression of hope that S&S will open a
discussion of this vital issue.
The passage from Marx is clearly intended to highlight the
source of individual creativity in the accumulation of prior
necessary conditions the quiet role of many laborers and
creators in the achievement of the individual work of genius. The
genius is working with materials handed down from many others.
This, however, most certainly does not mean that there are
guarantees of a solution to every problem that arises, and our
correspondent is quite correct to point this out. And her request
for further discussion of the nuclear waste issue should be
regarded as a call for papers!
A final item may be mentioned. In The New York Times of
October 21, 2000 (B9) there appeared a brief survey on recent and
not-so-recent novels about academia, by Sarah Boxer, entitled
"Satire in the Ivory Tower Gets Rough." The earliest novel
discussed is Mary McCarthy's The Groves of Academe (1952), about a
literature professor who tries to protect his job by spreading the
(false) rumor that he is a blacklisted Communist. For each of the
novels surveyed in tabular form, there is a column for "the
periodicals," and SCIENCE & SOCIETY is listed as mentioned in
McCarthy's novel, along with four other journals. Unfortunately,
S&S doesn't make the cut in any of the more recent novels, but
again, I suggest an upbeat interpretation of this fact: the novels,
as Boxer makes clear, tend to focus less and less on politics and
more and more on sex, sexual harassment, and sexual perversion, as
time moves forward, so it may be neither surprising nor
particularly lamentable that S&S does not figure in the more recent
works.
--------------<>---------------
Strolling across the new campus of Complutense University on the
outskirts of Madrid, in March 1999, I was struck upon seeing this
slogan, painted on a wall: "La economía es de gente, no de curvas!"
("Economics is about people, not curves!"). Anyone who has not had
the pleasure of instruction in contemporary academic economics may
not fully appreciate the students' sense of being tormented by
"curves": diagrammatic representations of relationships among
variables. (Think of intersecting supply and demand curves.) The
slogan rejects abstract and quantitative theory in economics and
by extension in the human disciplines generally in favor of
study of concrete, historical social reality.
I had no idea at the time that the "people vs. curves" slogan
I witnessed would turn out to be prophetic. In June 2000 a group
of French students assembled a petition, published on the web,
complaining about the current state of economics: its
indiscriminate use of mathematics; the "repressive domination" by
neoclassical theory; and the exclusion of alternative, critical
approaches. The students called upon the economics profession to
engage with the empirical and the concrete, to avoid "scientism,"
to embrace "a pluralism of approaches adapted to the complexity of
economic objects and to the uncertainty surrounding most of the big
economic questions," and to pursue reforms "to rescue economics
from its autistic and socially irresponsible state." The petition
resulted in the launching of the Post-Autistic Economics Movement,
which has spread like wildfire among students in France and Spain,
with growing numbers of correspondents in other countries as well.
On June 21, Le Monde reported on the movement and solicited
statements from leading economists worldwide. A conference to
produce more detailed proposals was held in December 2000. Since
then the movement has continued to grow and develop. (1)
The economics establishment, for the most part, has been
waiting to see if the storm will pass. One noteworthy response
came from Professor Robert Solow of MIT, Noble Laureate and
progenitor of the "neoclassical" growth model that has recently
become a staple of courses in macroeconomic theory. Writing in Le
Monde, January 3, 2001, Solow called the students' position "an
exaggerated reaction to this minority group [of highly mathematical
theorists], or a disguised attack upon something else." Concerning
the dominance of neoclassical theory, Solow characterized that
theory as follows: households and firms are rational; prices and
wages are flexible, so that goods and labor markets "find their
equilibrium"; and competition is "almost perfect." All of this,
however, Solow noted, has been called into question by neoclassical
economists themselves, who now study incomplete markets, imperfect
competition, rigid prices, asymmetric information, and other
complexities. We can all agree, the argument goes, that the simple
model is not adequate; the challenge is to find ways to go beyond
it without becoming immersed in undue complexity. In short, the
students to the extent they are not engaging in irrational
debate "relevant to doctrine, even ideology" are stating what
everyone already knows: that progress in science requires
continuing work to clear the path from abstract and simple theory
to ever more complex layers of reality. "Everyone would like to
see the real needs of the students satisfied, without sacrificing
necessary rigor. That can certainly be done." (2)
Now the students' movement, with its call for pluralism and
for "critical and reflective thought," is a remarkably positive
development, and it is a sign of their potential that top guns like
Solow have emerged to engage with them. I find, however, that an
attempt to come to grips with Solow's argument also raises some
questions concerning the students' position. or perhaps concerning
ambiguities in the statement of that position reflecting the
coalition character of the movement.
The hallmark of the Solow response, after all, is its
reasonableness. We all want the same thing, he says: good applied
economics, relevant to real-life problems and issues. In his
subtle deprecation of "ideology," however, Solow fails to note the
ideological role of his own neoclassical consensus. The religion
of the "free market" is closely connected to the abstractions of
rationality, competition and equilibrium as summarized by Solow.
But when these abstractions are questioned, their proponents say
that of course no one believes in them any more! We are concerned,
they insist, with the messy world of limited information, limited
competition, non-equilibrium behavior, etc. Trying to pin this
down is, as one of my colleagues once put it, like "boxing with
jello." Or, to cite a phrase from the philosopher Hilary Putnam,
neoclassical economics "keeps a double set of books" (quoted in
Vivian Walsh, Rationality, Allocation, and Reproduction, p. 6).
One set is for undergraduate students, politicians and journalists:
it promotes the social optimality of "perfect" competition and the
"free" market. The other set is brought out whenever critics, such
as the students organized in the post-autistic economics movement,
try to get to the bottom of this pervasive pro-capitalist ideology.
Consider Solow's main points summarizing the neoclassical
position. First, the claim that "households and firms" are
rational actors reveals an unexamined assumption: the economy's
fundamental units are "households and firms" not, to go directly
to the point, social classes (and individuals insofar as they act
as representatives of classes). Solow invites us to join him at
the frontiers of economic science in questioning the postulate of
rational behavior; he does not, however, question his conception of
the actors as such. Second, the assumption that "markets" are in
(or close to) "equilibrium" fails to address the central claim of
the only other theoretical tradition to confront this issue.
"Equilibrium" is always incomplete when the core relationship
determining wage rates is antagonistic; moreover, the apparent
concordance of individual rational wills in the market is a surface
manifestation of an underlying social reality involving domination,
exploitation, and oppression. This alternative tradition, of
course, is Marxism. (I cannot, of course, develop the argument
fully here.) Finally, we are urged to abandon "almost perfect
competition" in favor of various forms of market imperfection.
Again, the study of power is recommended, but it is limited in
advance to market power, ignoring the pervasive and immanent forms
of social power associated with the unequal distribution of
property in capitalist economies. This latter structure of power
is most clearly manifest when markets are functioning well, and
competition (among capitalists) is "perfect" i.e., market power
is absent.
Continue to next Page